The Market is a Process, not a Decision Mechanism

Veronique de Rugy testified,

But unlike in the marketplace, the incentives for good management in government are very weak. For instance, even though lawmakers are expected to pursue the “public interest,” they make decisions that use other people’s money rather than their own. This means that their exposure to the risk of a bad decision is fairly limited, and there is little to no reward for spending taxpayers’ money wisely or providing a service effectively or efficiently

This is standard public choice theory, and it is not wrong. But it is not persuasive to those who believe that moral authority is or ought to be sufficient to overcome such problems.

I think that many commentators contrast the market and government as mechanisms for making decisions. In this contrast, the market sometimes has an efficiency advantage, but government is presumed to have a moral-authority advantage.

Instead, think of the market as a process for testing hypotheses. The process is brutally empirical, winnowing out losing strategies and poor execution. In contrast, elections are a much weaker testing mechanism. Elections are unable to winnow out sugar subsidies, improvident loan guarantees, schools that produce bad outcomes, etc.

It is a lack of understanding of this dynamic that leads some people to surprised that healthcare.gov does not work as well as one of the leading commercial web sites. I keep trying to reiterate, as I do on this podcast, that something like Amazon is a rare survivor of a tournament. The private sector produced plenty of business ideas and software systems that were as bad as Obamacare and healthcare.gov, but those get winnowed out.

A Famous NYT Columnist Looks at the Minimum Wage and Income Inequality

He tries to offer a balanced view.

The federal minimum did not change from 1981 to 1990, causing its inflation-adjusted value to fall 30 percent during that time. Wages in the bottom of the income distribution fell sharply, even more sharply than they have in the last decade. The inflation-adjusted wage of a worker at the 20th percentile of the distribution dropped 9.5 percent from 1981 to 1990, according an analysis of government data in the forthcoming book “The State of Working America, 12th Edition,” by the Economic Policy Institute.

…Since 1990, though, the minimum wage has risen. If you’re trying to understand why every income group except for the affluent has taken an income cut over the last decade, you probably shouldn’t put the minimum wage at the top of your list of causes.

And if you are trying to guess which NYT columnist wrote this, you probably shouldn’t put Paul Krugman on your list of possible authors. Cross off Tyler Cowen, also, although he did link to the column. Continue reading

Forgotten Macroeconomic History

From Paul Volcker, interviewed by Martin Feldstein in the Journal of Economic Perspectives.

[Early in 1980, President] Carter was obviously under pressure, so he triggered a provision of law that
permitted the Federal Reserve to put on credit controls…We said, “Okay, you’re going to have a reserve requirement on credit cards—if credit cards exceed past peaks, you would have a reserve requirement.” We did that knowing, we’re now in March, the peak in credit card use comes in November and December. We were way below it so there was no possibility that this was going to become a factor for some time…The economy at that point fell like a rock. People were cutting up credit cards, sending in the pieces to the President as their patriotic duty. Mobile home and automobile sales dropped within the space of a week or so. The money supply, we didn’t know why the money supply was dropping, but all of the sudden the money supply was down 3 percent in a week or something…Well, it was a recession alright, the economy went down, but it was an artificial recession. As soon as we took off the credit controls in June, the economy began expanding again

Credit rationing seems to be quite powerful. Recall that before the late 1980s, interest-rate regulations ensured that when interest-rates rose, the depository institutions would find themselves without money to lend for mortgages, and that was usually enough to bring about a recession.

Margin Requirements and Entrance Fees

Tyler Cowen writes,

Imagine that financial institutions and traders have to hold large quantities of T-Bills (and similar assets) to participate in financial markets. That may be to satisfy collateral requirements, to meet government regulations, to be credible in private market transactions, and so on.

Think of what AIG was doing when it was writing credit default swaps on mortgage securities. It was taking tail risk by writing out-of-the-money options. If you believe Gary Gorton, they were fine, except that in 2008 their counterparties demanded collateral that they did not have, not because the options were in the money but because the options were closer to being in the money.

Today, if you want to pick up the nickels that you can earn by taking tail risk, you need to put up more margin. What Tyler is suggesting is that this increases the demand for safe assets relative to what it was prior to 2008. So even if the real return on T-bills is negative, they are worth it for financial institutions who use them to meet margin requirements on trades that enable them to make a profit.

If the financial institution is helping the economy by taking the tail risk, then it’s all fine. But Tyler suggests that the financial institution is not helping the economy (AIG was an enabler of the housing bubble). In that case, we would be better off with less tail-risk taking, which in turn would reduce the demand for safe assets and lead to a better allocation of saving and investment.

Stricter bank regulation may or may not help. The effect of risk-based capital regulations was to increase the demand for AAA-rated securities, which in turn increased the demand for credit default swaps written by AIG. So that was a case in which stricter bank regulation actually created (apparent) profit opportunities in taking tail risk. If regulation still has that effect, then it will increase the fundamental distortion in financial markets.

Business Psychology, Business Reality, AD-AS, and PSST

Nick Rowe writes,

For an open economy, like Canada, a lot of our PSSTs are with foreigners. Americans especially. That’s why Canadian recovery depends on US recovery, even though we have our own monetary policy so we can make our own AD curve shift independently of the US AD curve, if we want to. The Canadian recovery has been slow because the US recovery has been even slower. We can’t rebuild some of our PSSTs until the Americans rebuild some of theirs. We are waiting for the Americans to join in our cross-border PSSTs.

One way to think about PSST vs. AD-AS is to think about reversible or irreversible shifts in patterns of specialization and trade. If it’s reversible, then AD-AS is probably the best way to think about it. Because of excess inventory, housing construction and durable goods manufacturing are cut back, but that gets reversed when inventory/sales ratios get back down to normal levels. If it’s not reversible, then PSST may be the best way to think about it.

Now, on to business psychology and business reality.

If you like the old paradigm, then think of business psychology as if it were aggregate demand and business reality as if it were aggregate supply.

In business reality, opportunity can be high or low, and adversity can be high or low. Four possibilities for the overall state of business reality:

1. High-opportunity, low-adversity would describe an economy unleashed. This is a rare combination. Maybe the U.S. in the post-WWII hegemonic period? Maybe the parts of the Chinese economy that were freed by reforms? There are lots of opportunities to create new patterns of sustainable specialization and trade, but old patterns are not heavily threatened.

2. Low-opportunity, high-adversity. This typically reflects major government policy mistakes. Wage-price controls in the U.S. in the early 1970s? Hyperinflation in Zimbabwe. There are few opportunities to create new patterns of sustainable specialization and trade, and old patterns become unprofitable.

3. High-opportunity, high-adversity. This would be a very dynamic economy. The 1920s in the U.S.? 1990-2007 in much of the world? New patterns of sustainable specialization and trade are created, while old patterns break down.

4. Low-opportunity, low-adversity. This would be a relatively stagnant economy. Think of sectors where regulation restricts entry (health care and education come to mind). It’s hard to get into business and hard to be driven out of business.

Now, superimpose on this business reality the state of business psychology. Are entrepreneurs highly attuned to opportunities, or are they relatively timid? Are incumbent businesses highly attuned to adversity, or are they relatively blithe? These psychological conditions affect overall employment. The four possible psychological conditions:

1. High-opportunity, low-adversity. Something like the late 1990s, when new firms are chasing opportunities but old firms are not seeing the handwriting on the wall (Amazon expands, but Borders does not realize that its under threat).

2. Low-opportunity, high-adversity. You have the 1930s, or the past five years. Old firms are firing, because they are very attuned to adversity, but new firms are not thriving and growing.

3. High-opportunity, high-adversity. The economy is dynamic, and everybody knows it. Rapid restructuring takes place. The telecom industry in the U.S., where hundreds of thousands of telephone operators lost their jobs, but the cell phone industry created even more jobs.

4. Low-opportunity, low-adversity. An economy that tunes out the dynamism in the world. The economy fails to restructure, but few people get fired. Japan in the 1990s?

Note that this is close to the way Schumpeter thought about things. Note that “stagnation” can be primarily in business reality (#4 in the first list) or primarily in business psychology (#2 in the second list). Possibly both.

Normal Macro and Financial Crises: Road Friction and Flat Tires

Economists these days seem to want to describe two financial regimes. One is a “normal” regime, which can be regulated by conventional monetary policy. The other is a “crisis” regime, which cannot. Here is a metaphor to think about:

Imagine the economy as a car, with Fed monetary policy consisting of pressing on the accelerator pedal. The Fed tries to maintain a constant speed, and sometimes that means pushing hard on the accelerator and other times it means letting up. In the normal regime, the Fed just deals with road friction and hills.

In the crisis regime, the car has a flat tire. The Fed can press really hard on the accelerator pedal, and yet the car is not going to go as fast as people want.

Until recently, macroeconomic theory focused on the normal regime, dealing with road friction and hills. What are the microfoundations? What policy rules work best? etc.

But what about the crisis regime? Scott Sumner’s view would be that there is no such regime. He would say that we are seeing a normal regime in which the Fed has stubbornly failed to press hard enough on the accelerator pedal.

When I hear mainstream economists praise TARP, I think they believe that troubled banks were the macroeconomic equivalent of a flat tire, and you needed TARP to patch the tire. Perhaps this is correct. However, I do not think we can tell this story very well by using the models that were designed to describe the normal regime. As of now, I think that there is a huge gap between mainstream intuition, which thinks in terms of the flat tire, and mainstream modeling, which deals with road friction. In particular, treating financial markets as if they were just another potential source of road friction is probably not going to cut it.

I also do not think that “the zero bound” is the flat tire.

What might be the flat tire is an adverse equilibrium in an economy with multiple equilibria. Think of the economy as having channels of trust. When the channels of trust are open, we have the good equilibrium. When the channels of trust are closed, we have the bad equilibrium. Finance is particularly subject to these multiple equilibria. If people believe that financial instruments are safe, then borrowers can obtain lenient credit at low rates. But in an adverse equilibrium, creditors have doubts, and borrowers are constrained.

In the adverse equilibrium, there is less economic activity. This might explain the intuition that the financial crisis was horrible, and bailing out banks kept things from getting worse. However, it does not necessarily support the intuition that fiscal policy and quantitative easing are helpful.

And I do not necessarily endorse this particular model of the flat tire.

Richard Robb on the Origins of the Financial Crisis

He writes An Epistemology of the Financial Crisis, appearing in the current issue of Critical Review.

Subprime mortgages retained by U.S. banks for their own portfolios performed at least as badly as those they securitized for sale to others….A study by Wei Jiang, Ashlyn Nelson, and Edward Vytlacil [various versions available] examined one large lender and concluded that mortgage “loans remaining on the bank’s balance sheet are, ex post, of owrse quality than sold loans.” They concluded that RMBS [residential mortgage backed securities] investors had information advantages over banks. This is the very opposite of the view that banks sold the worst loans to unsuspecting third parties.

Robb’s theme is that the crisis was caused by imperfect knowledge rather than greed/adverse incentives. I have many comments

1. This same theme may be found in Jerry Muller’s similarly titled Our Epistemological Depression and my The Financial Crisis: Moral Failure or Cognitive Failure?, neither of which hare cited by Robb.

2. It is no surprise that Robb did not see the articles by Muller or me, nor is it likely that many people will see Robb’s. The mainstream narrative is available to everyone, while our narrative has been relegated to the most obscure publication outlets.

3. Robb writes,

One clue to what went wrong comes from a study that Fitch conducted [may be found here] on borrowers who defaulted within six months of taking out a mortgage. The study looked closely at 45 “early payment defaulters” from 2006. [It] found that 66 percent of them committed “occupancy fraud,” falsely claiming that they intended to occupy the home.

There are some forms of fraud that are often the fault of the lender, and the borrower is relatively blameless. Overstating borrower’s income is an example. But when it comes to occupancy fraud, you have to blame the borrower, and for lenders it is one of the most difficult forms of fraud to detect prior to making the loan. However, blaming the borrowers runs counter to the conventional narrative.

4. Contrary to what I have written, Robb argues that lenient risk-based capital rules for highly-rated mortgage securities were not implemented soon enough to be implicated in the financial crisis. On the Recourse Rule, a 2001 regulation that some of us believe encouraged subprime securitization, Robb writes,

While on the margin the Recourse Rule encouraged investment in highly rated ABS [asset backed securities], the incentives were not so great as to justify holding these securities unless banks thought they were safe.

5. Robb writes,

An unambiguous regulatory failure was the decision to allow Lehman Brothers to fail. The market expected the U.S. Treasury to cobble together a last-minute rescue over the weekend….largely because…Bear Stearns, had been rescued six months earlier by being absorbed into JPMorgan Chase. Lehman was 25 times large4r than Bear Stearns and far more interconnected…the Securities and Exchange Commission had no plan for an orderly transfer of clients’ assets…institutional clients with claims over $5000,000 had to wait until the summer of 2013.

6. According to Robb, the financial community never expected house prices to decline. But I would like to point out that you cannot just look at what investors were expecting on average. Instead, think of investors as assigning probabilities to various paths for house prices. I think it is fair to say that investors under-estimated the probability of a large decline in house prices. However, a sophisticated investor would not have assigned a zero probability to a path in which house prices declined.

7. Robb views post-crisis risk aversion as a major source of problems. He provides examples of assets that in hindsight were ridiculously undervalued by investors.

during a crisis, they learn to be skeptical of the probabilities, no matter how those probabilities are presented.

All in all, it is one of the most provocative essays I have read on the financial crisis.

Cognitive Capture

Acemoglu and Robinson write,

the excess returns of connected firms may be a reflection of the perception of the market (and likely a correct perception) that during turbulent times there will be both heightened policy discretion and even more of the natural tendency of government officials and politicians to rely on the advice of a small network of confidants. For Timothy Geithner this meant relying on, and appointing to powerful positions, financial executives from the firms he was connected to and felt comfortable with. But then, there is no guarantee that these people would not give advice favoring their firms, knowingly or perhaps subconsciously (for example, they may be under the grips of a worldview that increases the perceived importance of their firm’s survival for the health of the US economy).

This refers to an “event study” that looks at how the prices of different financial firms responded to the announcement that Timothy Geithner would be Treasury Secretary. Pointer from Mark Thoma.

I tend to discount event studies. For one thing, I suspect that there is a lot of “survivor bias” in that event studies that fail to lead to results that show something the authors want to show probably never see the light of day. But I happen to agree with the hypothesis that financial regulators are subject to cognitive capture by the large financial firms.

Cosmos and Taxis

A new journal that looks interesting.

emergent orders are unplanned and exhibit orderly development trajectories, but only some of them are spontaneous orders in the sense of providing easily interpreted feedback to order participants. Examples of emergent orders that are not spontaneous in the sense of Hayek or Polanyi are civil society, the ecosystem, and human cultures.

That is from the editorial introduction by David Emanuel Andersson. Pointer from Jason Collins.

Knowledge, Power, and PSST

James DeLong invited me to connect the two during the Q&A period here. What I would say is this:

PSST says that in a complex economy, employment fluctuates as unsustainable patterns of trade fall apart and new sustainable patterns get created. In that context, government spending creates new patterns that are unsustainable, such as those in now-failed “green energy” firms that received loan guarantees. The patterns that government creates tend to be unsustainable because of a knowledge-power discrepancy. Government has the power to command resources, but it does not have the knowledge that the market system provides about how to use resources.

So that is the sense in which one might relate the two.