From Frederick Taylor’s The Downfall of Money:
In the end, no one really got their money, not even the Americans. Germany used the American loans it received under the 1924 Dawes plan to pay reparations to the French and the British, who in turn used the money to service their own debts to the USA. Then, during the Great Depression, all the major powers, including Germany, France and Britain, effectively defaulted on what they owed to America, and into the bargain the Germans defaulted on reparations.
This reminded me of one of Tyler Cowen’s mantras, that we are not as wealthy as we thought we were. His implied model of recent economic events is that we had illusory wealth during the housing bubble and then reality bites. Some random thoughts:
1. Taylor’s picture of the 1920s suggests a possible wealth-illusion story for the Great Depression. The Germans did not think that they were going to pay anywhere near the full amount of reparations, so they did not count that full amount in their liabilities. However, the Allies were counting on receiving the full amount of reparations (as my previous post on the book indicates, the citizens were led to expect even more than the political leaders were really going to try to collect). In effect, reparations were being double-counted as aggregate wealth, with consumers in the Allied countries counting them as assets but without offsetting liabilities in German households. Then, around 1930, Allied households finally marked down their wealth, and you had the Great Depression.
2. Macroeconomists know that Keynesian fiscal policy effectiveness depends on wealth illusion. The question “Are government bonds net wealth?” must be answered “yes” in order for deficit spending to raise aggregate demand. Otherwise, if Barro-Ricardian equivalence holds (so that the increased wealth of the holders of government bonds is offset by the decreased wealth of households who have marked up their future tax liabilities), then deficits are not clearly expansionary.
3. In theory, wealth illusions do not have to be destabilizing. Economic activity does not have to rise and fall just because people have higher or lower perceptions of wealth. Complete wage and price flexibility would be sufficient to maintain full employment. I am not sure that complete wage and price flexibility is even necessary. However, in practice it seems likely that wealth illusions would prove to be destabilizing.
4. From a PSST perspective, one can imagine all sorts of patterns of trade that depend on perceptions of wealth. When wealth illusions break down, it is not as if all households take an equally proportionate hit. Some households lose more than others. For example, when the housing bubble broke, people who had a lot of their (illusory) wealth in housing lost more than people who did not. So when (illusory) wealth is redistributed, old patterns of specialization and trade become unsustainable, and there will be unemployment until new patterns are established.
5. One could argue that the increase in government debt financed by quantitative easing is fostering a wealth illusion in countries where it is taking place. Indeed, that is in some sense the intent–see point (2). Perhaps we should be more worried than we are about how the process of unwinding this wealth illusion can be accomplished without pain. Actually, I am plenty worried about it.