Macroeconomics of the crisis, 6

Tyler Cowen has a short paper on the topic.

The key point is that in the short run we want economic activity to fall in ways that will curb the spread of the virus. In the long run, we want economic activity to come back.

In my view, the primary channel by which a short-term reduction in economic activity leads to a long-term decline is the financial channel. I have an essay on that, which I will post below the fold.

The Government as Financial Intermediary Responding to the Virus Crisis

by Arnold Kling

I remember reading once that it is still not understood how the giraffe manages to pump an adequate blood supply all the way up to its head; but it is hard to imagine that anyone would therefore conclude that giraffes do not have long necks.

–Robert Solow, “On Theories of Unemployment.” American Economic Review. March, 1980

Economists “see” the economy through the lens of simple mathematical models. Robert Solow saw a danger of this. When reality and one’s preferred model conflict, the temptation to nonetheless stick to the model can make an economist dangerous. I worry that mainstream economists are guilty of this, trying to apply a model of “aggregate supply and demand” inappropriately to a complex economy.

The direct effects of the virus crisis on GDP are relatively small. The sectors that are most affected are travel and entertainment, and the output lost in these sectors is temporary. It is the indirect effects, multiplied by the financial sector, that create the potential for a massive economic collapse.

In other words, in the absence of financial risk, the economic damage of the virus crisis would be minor. The main macroeconomic policy issue raised by the crisis concerns what to do about financial risk. Unfortunately, mainstream economists do not have a “go-to” model of financial risk. Instead, they face the choice of using the misguided “aggregate demand/aggregate supply” model or remaining silent on policy.

Models are metaphors, and “aggregate supply and demand” is a particularly weak metaphor. But rather than critique this metaphor, what I will do here is propose an alternative metaphor for navigating the virus crisis: government as a financial intermediary.

What Financial Intermediaries Do

As individuals, we prefer to issue risky, long-term liabilities and to hold riskless, short-term assets. The financial sector accommodates this by issuing riskless, short-term assets liabilities backed by risky, long-term liabilities assets.

This process takes place in layers. For example, suppose that a firm creates a risky, long-term asset by starting a new project. The firm finances this project in part by issuing debt, which is somewhat less risky and not as long-term. A bank invests in the debt, and the bank issues checking accounts which are riskless, short-term assets to households (liabilities to banks).

The foregoing description is greatly simplified. In modern finance, there are many layers in the middle of transforming the risky, long-term liabilities created at the edges of the nonfinancial economy. These layers include exotic financial instruments, such as options and other derivatives. The layers involve many institutions, including nonfinancial corporations, mutual funds, pension funds, insurance companies, investment banks, and commercial banks.

Governments participate in the financial intermediation process. They issue fiat money, which is a riskless, short-term instrument. But they also bolster the other layers in the financial system, by issuing loan guarantees and subsidizing particular forms of credit. For example, when the government provides deposit insurance, this helps banks to present their short-term liabilities as riskless, even though deposits are backed by risky, long-term assets.

Financial Crisis

A financial crisis occurs when there is a widespread, cascading loss of confidence in what were formerly considered riskless financial assets. For example, if people were to lose confidence in bank deposits, there could be a “run” on banks. That in turn would require banks to shrink, which would mean that firms that depend on bank loans could not continue to operate.

The virus crisis threatens to cause a financial crisis. For example, airlines are heavily financed by debt, and the sudden, sharp drop in travel means that they will not be able to meet the payments on that debt. That in turn threatens the banks or other financial intermediaries to which the airlines owe money.

The government can intervene in a financial crisis, using a variety of financial instruments and offering them to a variety of layers. For example, in the case of airlines, the government could offer direct cash assistance to the airlines so that they can meet their debt payments. Alternatively, the government could offer loan guarantees to the airlines. This would force the shareholders of airlines to bear losses, but it would protect banks and other lenders. Alternatively, the government could allow banks to write down the loans to airlines, letting bank capital fall below regulatory standards but continuing to insure bank deposits. I term this latter approach “forbearance.”

Picking Winners and Losers

One concern that the government faces is that it must preserve its own credibility as a financial intermediary. If bondholders lose confidence in the financial soundness of the government, then they will charge a high interest rate, and this may make it infeasible for the government to borrow. The government will then have to print money to pay its bills, a process that risks hyperinflation. To avoid these scenarios, the government must be judicious in choosing how to backstop the financial sector.

The government cannot afford to meet every desire for financial assistance. Government intervention in a financial crisis inevitably involves picking winners and losers. In the airline example, if the government offers cash assistance, then airline shareholders are winners. If the government offers loan guarantees, then the creditors of airlines are winners, but airline shareholders may be losers. If the government offers forbearance, then banks are winners, but they may choose to let the airlines go under, making other creditors of the airlines losers.

With government acting as a financial intermediary, future taxpayers may be losers. For example, if the government issues debt to fund cash assistance to airlines, then future taxpayers will have to pay higher taxes in order to repay that debt. If the government instead uses loan guarantees, then if some airlines go bankrupt, future taxpayers will have to make good the losses. If the government engages in forbearance but the banks eventually become insolvent, then taxpayers will have to help bail out the deposit insurance fund.

Offering guidelines

The process of picking winners and losers is bound to be discretionary, and it is bound to be political. There are no clear rules. At best, economists can offer guidelines.

One classic guideline comes from Walter Bagehot, who said that a lender of last result should lend freely, against good collateral, at a penalty rate. Unfortunately, this guideline is of little help in today’s economy. Are the assets of a struggling airline good collateral? If not, then are the outstanding loans made by a bank to an airline good collateral for lending to the bank?

Instead, let me propose the following:

It is in the public interest to try to maximize the way that assistance helps to re-start economic activity. Instead, assistance which primarily serves to make whole the losses of particular constituents is simply a wealth transfer, not an economic stimulus. This suggests giving assistance that either directly or indirectly provides working capital to firms. Loans to financially strapped households also may fall in this category.

The approach that seems most likely to serve these purposes is to offer forbearance to banks, while “jawboning” them to provide working capital to nonfinancial firms and consumer loans to households. As banks deplete their capital, the risk to the deposit insurance fund will grow. But this approach probably offers the greatest potential for improving economic activity with the smallest burden on taxpayers.

Note: Kevin Warsh is thinking along similar lines. His proposal has the Fed participating in bank lending, rather than my combination of forbearance plus jawboning. Either way, banks would be involved in the decision of who to save and how to save them.

14 thoughts on “Macroeconomics of the crisis, 6

  1. This seems to be the Canadian strategy for Ensuring economic resilience. It is relying on established federal institutions for business loans so the tactics are different than what is required for American banks, but the strategy is the same (I think). The tactic turns on existing loan officers being acutely aware of COVID-19 related cashflow issues.

  2. “The key point is that in the short run we want economic activity to fall in ways that will curb the spread of the virus.”

    This seems so utterly and completely complacent and, I do note this with some irony, as the author literally wrote the book on modern complacency.

    In a non-complacent society, we would be curbing the the spread of the virus while simultaneously minimizing the economic costs. Is this too much to ask?

    • So what would that mean? Huge expansions of telemedicine? Shipping blood pressure monitors to every household? Are there machines that can act as a remote stethoscope?

      The reason you would want economic activity to fall is that a lot of that activity in the US appears to be reliant in people providing services face to face, or if not providing the services face to face, congregating in close quarters while working, like in a restaurant kitchen that has been designed to take up the least space possible to both save on rent and to speed up cooking.

      • “The reason you would want economic activity to fall is that a lot of that activity in the US appears to be reliant in people providing services face to face”

        But, based the best available evidence, most of the face to face interactions are between people that are most immune to the adverse effects of the virus. Why should we be discouraging such things provided that the least immune are protected?

        Until you can answer that question, then you aren’t answering any question related to this.

        • If most people under the age of 40 get the virus, how do you keep them from infecting people over the age of 40? Especially given that places like nursing facilities and hospitals rely on staff under the age of 40, it doesn’t seem realistic that you can keep older people from getting the virus if lots of younger people have it.

    • What the hell are you talking about? How exactly are we going to both control the virus and keep packed clubs packed?

      Cuz what he meant by ‘certain economic sectors contracting’ is ‘the packed clubs aren’t packed any more’.

      • “What the hell are you talking about?”

        I’m talking about utilitarianism and economics.

        Care to dive in or are you just going to dismiss this as mere reactionism?

    • Of course it’s “too much to ask”. Almost silly, in fact, because as is very clear:

      most Actions to Curb the Spread INCREASE economic costs.
      What are the optimal trade-offs?
      Everybody wants to end the spread. Everybody wants to minimize the costs.
      What should be done, now?

      2 week, or more, total lockdown minimizes spread, but has high costs.
      Relaxed lockdown-lite reduces spread, not minimize, with a lower cost.
      No gov’t action now might have the lowest early costs, with the highest spread — and the cost might rapidly increase if hospitals are overwhelmed by severe cases. Tho the “cost” might then be borne by doctors & nurses, and of the elderly that die who could have been saved. (Lower pension payments?)

      Not all reduced activity has the same cost for the same reduction in spread, nor are all forms of spread the same.

      Your failure to specify your preferred tradeoffs imply some magic thinking that there are no tradeoffs.

      My tradeoff right now is to curb the spread, and worry about the costs a bit later. I expect better testing and better and cheaper treatments will be coming, so minimizing spread & problems now might also minimize total costs, but might not. Higher than minimum costs are OK if they minimize deaths & spread this week.

      Canada’s response to the 2008-2009 financial shock (thx RAD) seems good:
      provided $11 billion of additional credit support to 10,000 firms.

  3. “This would force the shareholders of airlines to bear losses, but it would protect banks and other lenders.”

    Sure, I am on board if you clawback all the bonuses paid via debt financed share buybacks for the last decade, zero out share holders, and make sure none of that BS takes place ever again.

    So we are really going down this road……..again! If so that Matt Stoller’s rule need to apply.

    https://mattstoller.substack.com

  4. “The sectors that are most affected are travel and entertainment, and the output lost in these sectors is temporary.”

    Uh, no. You are so wrong here and the data will show it very soon. Real estate contracts are being cancelled, construction projects are being cancelled, doctors offices are empty (ironically), and big purchases are being put off. What your models are not showing is FEAR! When people go to the grocery store frightened of catching the virus, see empty shelves, and people fighting over the last steak in has very real effects.

  5. There’s been a few articles lately about price gouging, people doing it, jurisdictions threatening to enforce laws against it, and retailers abandoning whole categories of products in order to avoid running afoul of those laws.

    Would you please consider giving your two cents on all that?

  6. Dan Mitchell also has a note about it.
    https://danieljmitchell.wordpress.com/2020/03/16/debating-the-best-economic-policy-response-to-coronavirus/#comment-274916

    Here’s my comment there:
    This is NOT any “black swan” event – it’s similar to SARS, and MERS, and even some to H1N1.

    Your solution is good tho:
    “firms would guard against black-swan events by having business interruption insurance and households would similarly protect themselves by setting aside funds in savings accounts. ”

    BUT – it’s too late. This is what should have happened after 2009. And, yes, it should happen for the future after this crisis.

    What we should do now, tho, is to allow businesses to apply for “business interruption insurance” payments, now, but as a gov’t loan. They get the cash, but repay it as a loan (pre-tax cost) in the future, rather than as an insurance premium.

    Plus they’re required to get insurance of a similar amount.

    The gov’t “actuarial” table should assume every 10 years there will be a similar business destroying pandemic. Premiums, and loan re-payments, should be based on that.

Comments are closed.